Leaving PIMCO.com

You are now leaving the PIMCO website.

Skip to Main Content
Economic and Market Commentary

The Real Lessons From the Plaza and Louvre Accords

Sustainable adjustments to trade imbalances require supportive monetary and fiscal policies – not just currency intervention.

This piece originally appeared in the Financial Times on 29 April 2025.

The September 1985 Plaza Accord and the subsequent February 1987 Louvre Accord are justly lauded today as significant successful examples of international economic policy cooperation.

These agreements aimed to engineer an orderly depreciation of a very overvalued U.S. dollar and to reduce what had become a massive U.S. trade deficit as well as to turn back the rising protectionist pressures triggered by it. In the event, by 1987 the orderly dollar depreciation had been delivered and by 1989, the trade deficit as a share of GDP had been cut by two-thirds. Plaza-Louvre: Mission Accomplished.

Direct foreign exchange currency market intervention has been widely believed to have played a significant, perhaps decisive, role in delivering the weaker dollar and smaller trade deficits. This, however, is a myth that has persisted.

It is an appealing one. Wouldn’t it be remarkable if a country could virtually eliminate its trade deficit simply by coordinating foreign exchange market intervention with like-minded allies? But it is also wrong. In fact, the historical record provides a much different set of lessons that should be relevant to any current discussion or plans for a so-called Mar-a-Lago currency agreement aimed at reducing the U.S. trade deficit.

In September 1985, representatives from the G-5 nations of the U.S., Germany, Japan, the U.K., and France convened to address the appreciation of the dollar. The resulting Plaza Accord committed the participating countries to coordinated foreign exchange interventions. The primary motivation was to alleviate protectionist pressures and reduce the U.S. trade deficit, which had reached about 3% of GDP.

Two years later, the Louvre Accord was signed in Paris. This agreement marked a shift in policy, as the participating nations concluded that the dollar had depreciated sufficiently and agreed to stabilize exchange rates around existing levels to prevent further volatility.

However, empirical evidence and academic research suggest that coordinated intervention, although symbolically significant, was not the primary driver of the dollar’s depreciation between 1985 and 1987.

Instead, it was the substantial easing of U.S. monetary policy under Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker that played the decisive role. Volcker by late 1984 had successfully broken the back of the double-digit inflation he inherited in 1979 and had plenty of room to cut interest rates. Indeed, between October 1984 (11 months prior to the Plaza Accord) and December 1986 (two months before the Louvre Accord), the Fed cut interest rates from 12% to 6%, and a weaker dollar soon followed and in near lockstep with these rate cuts.

U.S. fiscal consolidation was also crucial to reducing the trade deficit. Despite making initial tax cuts and defense spending increases in 1981, the Reagan administration in later years worked with Congress to enact significant fiscal tightening measures. These measures taken together reduced U.S. budget deficits by nearly 40% and were essential in narrowing the U.S. trade deficit in the context of an expanding economy. Crucially, the original Plaza Accord communiqués explicitly highlighted that fiscal adjustment in the U.S., Japan, and Germany would be required to reduce global trade imbalances, and, at least in the U.S., they were delivered.

Recent discussions have emerged regarding a potential “Mar-a-Lago Accord,” drawing analogies to the Plaza and Louvre Accords. Advocates such as economist Zoltan Pozsar and chair of the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers Stephen Miran have in the past discussed coordinated interventions to weaken the dollar, coupled with novel fiscal arrangements, including swapping short-dated U.S. Treasury holdings for long-dated or perpetual bonds held by foreign central banks. Additionally, some proponents suggest linking currency cooperation with security arrangements and tariff reductions.

The Plaza and Louvre Accords provide valuable historical lessons. While coordinated currency intervention can signal policy intent and temporarily influence exchange rates, sustainable adjustments require supportive monetary and fiscal policies. The proposed Mar-a-Lago Accord, while conceptually similar, faces distinct contemporary challenges, including limited monetary policy flexibility, uncertain fiscal consolidation prospects, and complex geopolitical considerations.

Policymakers must recognize that successful international coordination requires credible commitments across monetary, fiscal, and geopolitical dimensions, rather than relying solely on currency intervention.

Featured Participants

Tell us a little about you to help us personalize the site to your needs.

Terms and Conditions

Please read and acknowledge the following terms and conditions:

{{!-- Populated by JSON --}}

Select Your Location


Americas

Asia Pacific

  • Japan

Europe, Middle East & Africa

  • Europe
Back to top